What is Blended Finance and Is It Needed?

Interest in blended finance, it seems, is growing in popularity. Having personally designed and invested in multiple transactions involving blended finance structures, I felt it was time to take a step back from my usual discussion topics and describe what blended finance is, what conditions should be met for it to work well, and delve into the thornier question of whether it is even necessary.

What is Blended Finance?

Blended finance is a capital structure wherein more risk tolerant (“catalytic”) capital from philanthropic or government sources takes a first-loss position to more risk averse (“commercial” or “private sector”) capital, thereby mobilizing the risk-averse capital into impact investments that seek to achieve Sustainable Development Goals. This catalytic capital “de-risks” the investment opportunity, making it economically viable, typically by charging a rate of return that is considered below market, or not fully risk adjusted. Convergence provides examples of these structures here.

This blending of different types of capital together to achieve development impact is usually possible when three conditions are met. First, the risk of the investment opportunity is perceived to be high, usually because the sector or business model is earlier stage and therefore the risks harder to quantify. Second, to make the economics of the investment viable, the catalytic capital has to be willing to provide a degree of subsidy by earning a return that commercial investors perceive to be not fully risk-adjusted. Third, both types of capital have to see the investment opportunity as a “win-win.” This is usually possible if all parties are interested in achieving a development impact even if the secondary motivations for doing so might be different. The commercial capital might be driven by positive publicity or reputation enhancement as well as impact. It might also be motivated by the ability to make a larger investment than it otherwise would have. The catalytic capital, in turn, might be willing to make an investment that is expected to make a loss because it achieves social impact returns that are orders of magnitude larger than what could have been achieved through charitable giving alone. Donations by definition earn a -100% return, so philanthropic capital finds even a partially loss-making blended finance investment preferable to charitable giving, as any amount of capital that comes back can be reinvested.

Varying Opinions on Blended Finance

For some the idea of providing a subsidy through a blended finance is controversial. For example, a recent Stanford Social Innovation Review article argued that, “impact investors should not want to change the financial structure of an investment with a subsidy, as that would mask an investment’s true price and encourage investors to make investments they would otherwise avoid [resulting] in the wrong factories getting built and the wrong businesses getting support—a waste of financial resources and a missed opportunity to achieve social gains.”[1]

As economists will tell you, subsidies can (and do) fall prey to the law of unintended consequences. Take for example kerosene, a dangerous and highly polluting fossil fuel used for lighting by India’s rural poor, which is government subsidized. Unfortunately, the subsidy has resulted in a thriving black market and has had the unintended consequence of making cheaper, cleaner solar powered light sources less competitive. If the private sector is not willing to invest in something because risk adjusted returns cannot be earned, then (the argument goes) a subsidy must be destroying, not adding, value by inducing private investment to happen where the free market would have otherwise steered clear.

However, I think there are two strong arguments to be made in favor of blended finance, even with the risk of “distorting” the free market. As mentioned earlier, because many social enterprise business models are nascent and not well understood, there is a perceived higher risk to investing. Although the past cannot predict the future, investors are always looking to the past for data to determine what is likely to happen in the future. For this reason, blended finance helps build a market by creating a track record. By causing investments to happen, blended finance allows commercial investors to understand the risks better and get comfortable with them. Once the risks are known, they are easier to analyze and quantify. If done correctly, blended finance should enable the private sector to invest in the future on its own without subsidy. The microfinance sector went through a similar evolution. Some micro-finance institutions still receive subsidies, particularly in the form of soft loans, but by and large microfinance has achieved commercial scale and is able to attract private investment thanks in part to subsidies received in its earlier days.

Why Blended Finance is Necessary

This argument in favor is akin to the “infant industry” argument in economics. By catalyzing investment into these nascent sectors, blended finance helps to scale them up and commercialize. In its original form, the infant industry argument advocates in favor of subsidies or tariffs to protect early stage national industries from foreign competition, enabling them to achieve economies of scale and compete on an even playing field. While not a perfect comparison, this modified infant industry argument suggests that blended finance is helping to scale up social enterprise models to achieve commercialization to be able to compete with (or disrupt) incumbent status quo business models (or business as usual). The key to any infant industry argument of course is that the infant grows up and can stand on its own. The subsidy should therefore be temporary. If not, then the business model may be flawed and may never achieve scale and sustainability. Providers of catalytic capital should therefore monitor progress and keep an eye on this end goal.

Another strong argument in favor of blended finance is urgency. If markets are efficient, then capital should naturally flow to those social enterprise models that have good long term prospects. However, markets are not always efficient, and this process can be slow. Time is not on our side if we want to address the pressing needs of reducing poverty and the root causes of climate change. Catalytic capital is called “catalytic” for this reason: it helps mobilize money more quickly and in larger quantities than might happen otherwise. Advocates for blended finance often refer to this mobilization as getting from “billions to trillions.” To achieve the Sustainable Development Goals, trillions of investment is needed, and in order to achieve these volumes sooner rather than later, blended finance is pivotal.

So blended finance should be a bridge, not a crutch, and it should not distort the free market, but disrupt it in ways that replace older, inefficient ways of doing business with ones that sustainably benefit the environment and society. Getting to commercial scale and profitability should be the goal of every entrepreneur and every impact investor. Blended finance is just one tool in our tool kit, but it is a powerful one if wielded properly.

[1] “Almost Everything You Know About Impact Investing Is Wrong” (Stanford Social Innovation Review: Dec. 2018)

1 thought on “What is Blended Finance and Is It Needed?”

  1. Largely agree with you and it’s good to get the view of someone doing these deals. Some minor points to debate:

    1) The idea that all parties in the deal have some impact thinking. That is very much true in smaller scale deals, and social enterprise situations. But we’ve seen large deals where the top tier of capital is institutional money really just looking for returns and exposure in a new market at the right risk level. Of course you do note in your blog that sometimes the impact thinking is simply PR, so perhaps we’re closer on that one than it seems.

    2) The distortion issue. Yes, subsidies distort (whether or not they appear in a blended deal or are just straight grants). But sometimes the blended transaction is taking place in an already distorted market. This happens in climate and conservation situations, where the negative impacts of business as usual show up as environmental externalities. The point of the blended structure is for the catalytic capital to “pay for,” or internalize, the public benefit of taking a different approach. So, in a simple case, a subsidy for a solar deal may be correcting for the unpriced negative impacts of having kerosene be the dominant fuel source, for instance.

    The infant industry analogy is thought provoking, when one reflects back on the use of that argument in the 70s to set up protectionist markets that stalled development in some emerging economies. We do see lots of careful concern around this issue, and discussion of off-ramps, from both the donor community and the DFIs (see OECD Blended Finance Principles and DFI Blended Finance Working Group commentary).

    – Joan Larrea, CEO, Convergence Blended Finance

Comments are closed.